Extracting risk-neutral densities from option prices using mixture binomial trees

Since the stock market crash in October of 1987, prices of index options deviate significantly from Black-Scholes theory. This fact is prominently documented in the literature as the volatility smile (M. Rubinstein 1994). The pricing error is a sign that the assumptions of the model do not capture all relevant information embedded in option prices. As response to this problem, previous research has relaxed some of the underlying assumptions in order to arrive at more realistic prices. Examples are changes in the data generating process of the underlying security, e.g., jump diffusion or constant elasticity of variance models. We reverse this direction of thought: we take recorded option prices as given and estimate the implied pricing kernel that is consistent with current market valuations. To be flexible in the shape of the risk-neutral density and to allow probabilities to be non-Gaussian, we use the concept of mixture distributions. We apply our methodology to a recent dataset of options on the S&P 500 index future traded on the Chicago Mercantile Exchange. The data spans the year 1998 and contains settlement prices for 22497 American-style futures options.

[1]  S. Ross,et al.  Option pricing: A simplified approach☆ , 1979 .

[2]  F. Black,et al.  The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities , 1973, Journal of Political Economy.

[3]  David S. Bates The Crash of ʼ87: Was It Expected? The Evidence from Options Markets , 1991 .

[4]  S. Ross,et al.  The valuation of options for alternative stochastic processes , 1976 .

[5]  Lars E. O. Svensson,et al.  New Techniques to Extract Market Expectations from Financial Instrument , 1996 .

[6]  M. Rubinstein. Implied Binomial Trees , 1994 .

[7]  A. Lo,et al.  Nonparametric Estimation of State‐Price Densities Implicit in Financial Asset Prices , 1998 .

[8]  F. Longstaff Option Pricing and the Martingale Restriction , 1995 .

[9]  David S. Bates Jumps and Stochastic Volatility: Exchange Rate Processes Implicit in Thephlx Deutschemark Options , 1993 .

[10]  David S. Bates Dollar jump fears, 1984–1992: distributional abnormalities implicit in currency futures options , 1996 .

[11]  Andrew W. Lo,et al.  Nonparametric estimation of state-price densities implicit in financial asset prices , 1995, Proceedings of 1995 Conference on Computational Intelligence for Financial Engineering (CIFEr).

[12]  David S. Bates Post-&Apos;87 Crash Fears in S&P 500 Futures Options , 1997 .

[13]  David S. Bates The skewness premium: option pricing under asymmetric processes , 1994 .

[14]  Douglas T. Breeden,et al.  Prices of State-Contingent Claims Implicit in Option Prices , 1978 .

[15]  Ronald C. Savin,et al.  Aggressive acne treatment: as simple as one, two, three? , 1996, The Physician and sportsmedicine.

[16]  J. Campa,et al.  Implied Exchange Rate Distributions: Evidence from OTC Option Markets , 1997 .

[17]  Heinz Zimmermann State-Preference Theorie und Asset Pricing , 1998 .

[18]  M. Rubinstein.,et al.  Recovering Probability Distributions from Option Prices , 1996 .

[19]  William R. Melick,et al.  Recovering an Asset's Implied PDF from Option Prices: An Application to Crude Oil during the Gulf Crisis , 1997, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis.

[20]  J. Wei,et al.  Upper bounds for american futures options: A note , 1994 .

[21]  Allan M. Malz Using option prices to estimate realignment probabilities in the European Monetary System: the case of sterling-mark , 1996 .