Tail Risk Constraints and Maximum Entropy

Portfolio selection in the financial literature has essentially been analyzed under two central assumptions: full knowledge of the joint probability distribution of the returns of the securities that will comprise the target portfolio; and investors’ preferences are expressed through a utility function. In the real world, operators build portfolios under risk constraints which are expressed both by their clients and regulators and which bear on the maximal loss that may be generated over a given time period at a given confidence level (the so-called Value at Risk of the position). Interestingly, in the finance literature, a serious discussion of how much or little is known from a probabilistic standpoint about the multi-dimensional density of the assets’ returns seems to be of limited relevance. Our approach in contrast is to highlight these issues and then adopt throughout a framework of entropy maximization to represent the real world ignorance of the “true” probability distributions, both univariate and multivariate, of traded securities’ returns. In this setting, we identify the optimal portfolio under a number of downside risk constraints. Two interesting results are exhibited: (i) the left- tail constraints are sufficiently powerful to override all other considerations in the conventional theory; (ii) the “barbell portfolio” (maximal certainty/ low risk in one set of holdings, maximal uncertainty in another), which is quite familiar to traders, naturally emerges in our construction.

[1]  Robert M. Bell,et al.  Competitive Optimality of Logarithmic Investment , 1980, Math. Oper. Res..

[2]  Long Jiang,et al.  A Maximum Entropy Method for a Robust Portfolio Problem , 2014, Entropy.

[3]  H. Geman,et al.  Order Flow, Transaction Clock, and Normality of Asset Returns , 2000 .

[4]  W. Ziemba,et al.  Growth versus security in dynamic investment analysis , 1992 .

[5]  H. Kleinert,et al.  Rényi’s information transfer between financial time series , 2011, 1106.5913.

[6]  J. Hicks,et al.  Value and Capital , 2017 .

[7]  R. C. Merton,et al.  An Analytic Derivation of the Efficient Portfolio Frontier , 1972, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis.

[8]  Rongxi Zhou,et al.  Applications of Entropy in Finance: A Review , 2013, Entropy.

[9]  Damiano Brigo,et al.  Lognormal-mixture dynamics and calibration to market volatility smiles , 2002 .

[10]  Edward O. Thorp,et al.  Understanding the Kelly Criterion , 2011 .

[11]  A. Stuart,et al.  Portfolio Selection: Efficient Diversification of Investments , 1959 .

[12]  M. Richardson,et al.  A Direct Test of the Mixture of Distributions Hypothesis: Measuring the Daily Flow of Information , 1994, Journal of Financial and Quantitative Analysis.

[13]  N. Georgescu-Roegen The Entropy Law and the Economic Process , 1973 .

[14]  How Should We Use Entropy in Economics? Crises in Physics and Economics , 1999 .

[15]  J. Tobin Liquidity Preference as Behavior towards Risk , 1958 .

[16]  Stephen A. Ross,et al.  Mutual fund separation in financial theory—The separating distributions , 1978 .

[17]  Nassim Nicholas Taleb,et al.  Dynamic Hedging: Managing Vanilla and Exotic Options , 1997 .

[18]  Celia Anteneodo,et al.  Nonextensive statistical mechanics and economics , 2003, ArXiv.

[19]  George C. Philippatos,et al.  Entropy, market risk, and the selection of efficient portfolios , 1972 .

[20]  E. Thorp OPTIMAL GAMBLING SYSTEMS FOR FAVORABLE GAMES , 1969 .

[21]  John L. Kelly,et al.  A new interpretation of information rate , 1956, IRE Trans. Inf. Theory.

[22]  M. Frittelli The Minimal Entropy Martingale Measure and the Valuation Problem in Incomplete Markets , 2000 .

[23]  John Haigh Focus on Sport The Kelly criterion and bet comparisons in spread betting , 2000 .